Banking

Full-reserve banking

Full reserve banking

Let’s introduce a banker to those villagers, who sets up First Shell Bank. This bank is simply a location to store shells. This activity doesn’t really change anything. If Alice needs another fishing rod she still as to persuade the same people to lend her the money, although now this will just involve putting the shells in a different box in the bank.

This bank keeps all of its assets as reserves, and so cannot itself lend to Alice.

Bank currency

Alice has 10 shells at her bank. If she wants to pay Bob 10 shells for something, she can either take out and give him physical shells or inform the bank of a transfer.

If the bank allowed her to withdraw a claim on 10 shells, she could give this to Bob. This is how cash works.

Types of money

The supply of money has increased through the use of fractional reserves at the bank. There are different definitions of the money supply:

  • M0: physical cash outside of banks (90 in our example above)

  • MB: all cash (100)

  • M1: M0 and bank deposits (120)

Fractional-reserve banking

Banks

Banks get revenue from their lending activities. Their costs include identifying investment opportunities and paying interest to depositors.

Is the bank system more wasteful because it has reserves? Not really – reserves are needed because the bank deposits are on demand. If Alice received funds directly from each one she would keep some in reserve herself, in case someone demanded money back. What the bank does is:

  • Make identifying investment opportunities simpler

  • Matching short term depositors with long term borrowers

If Alice puts some of the money lent to her in the bank, this could have been lent out, recursively.

\(Total money supply = \dfrac{Base money}{Reserve ratio}\)

The \(money multiplier\), the ratio of total money supply to base money is equal to \(\dfrac{1}{Reserve ratio}\)

Investments and time requirements, and search costs for investment

Bank failure

Banks hold reserves to cushion against both an increase in withdrawals from depositors and in case their investments do not pay off. So what happens if reserves aren’t sufficient? This depends on whether the issue is on their liabilities (i.e. a run on the bank, causing a liquidity problem) or their assets (i.e. their investments turn sour, causing a solvency problem).

In the former case, the bank still has healthy assets but they may be unable to demand early repayment from those they have lent money to. One solution to this is for the bank itself to get a loan from another bank, to bridge this gap.

What if the underlying assets are weak and the bank cannot get a private loan? The bank fails. In addition to depositors not being able to access their money, this tends to increase the amount of reserves desired to be held by banks, decreasing the money supply.

The solvency of a bank depends on the quality of its assets, which may be hard for another bank to evaluate. This creates an information asymmetry problem, and leads to more cautious lending from banks.

Non-deposit financing of banks

Bank finance

If the bank wants to raise money for lending it can:

  • Attract more deposits

  • Raise equity

  • Issue debt

Let’s consider the latter two in more detail. Both issuing shares and debt will provide cash for reserves, but they create different risks. Repayments on deposits are made when depositors decide to take money out of the bank, repayments on equity are made when the bank decides to pay dividends, and repayments on debt are made as set out in the debt issue.

These present different risks – using deposits puts you at risk of depositors withdrawing all at the same time, debt means that you may not have income to pay your debts.

Banks use a mix of different methods of raising money, reflecting these risks and the different costs.

Banks can lend to each other on the interbank market, and often do on a short term basis.

Central banking

Central banks

Central banks are government institutions which manages a state’s currency.

Central banks can create base currency, including by paying interest on reserves held and by purchasing assets using new money.

Lender of last resort

While other banks may be able to finance a solvent bank with liquidity problems, a central bank may want to do this even if private banks do not, because of the knock on impact of the collapse of a bank.

This provides incentives for banks to take excessive risk. Central banks attempt to manage this risk elsewhere, for example with reserve requirements.

Central banks issue their own currency for commercial banks to hold as base money. The currency could be claims on gold, but doesn’t have to be, and today broadly isn’t.

Commercial banks then hold central bank currency as reserves, and control the supply of central bank money.

Controlling money supply

Central banks can manipulate the supply of money and inflation in many ways.

Reserve requirements

Central banks can set reserve requirements for banks. If binding, this affects the money multiplier.

Open market operations

In the US banks lend to one another. The US Federal Reserve (the Fed) takes a measure of different lending rates to construct the Federal Funds Effective Rate, and targets a value for this rate. The Fed engages in repos and reverse repos to create or remove money until this is hit.

In a repo the Fed buys a security from a bank with new cash, and with the agreement that the bank will repurchase the security at a specified date with a specified price. This increases the supply of money, and therefore reduces the cost of interbank borrowing. A reverse repo works the opposite way.

Quantitative easing is similar, and involves large scale purchases of assets. Unlike standard OMO quantitative easing target assets with a longer maturity, and so the central bank can simultaneously target the interbank overnight lending rate.

Undertaking such operations gives the central bank a balance sheet of financial assets.

Interest on reserves

Central banks can pay interest on the reserves held by commercial banks. This can be different for reserves above the required level.

Paying interest on required reserves increases the money supply and reduces the opportunity cost of depositing at the Fed. This removes the effective tax on reserves.

By paying interest on excess reserves the Fed reduces the incentive to lend elsewhere, and incentivises banks to hold additional reserves, compared to a given interbank lending rate.

Discount window

In addition to depositing at the central bank, banks can also borrow from it. This tends to be higher than interbank lending rates, and so is only used significantly in extreme circumstances.

In the UK it is this rate which is the official bank rate, with interbank lending rates (LIBOR) not directly managed.

Zero lower bound

If the central bank targets a lending rate of below 0%, a lender can obtain a better rate by holding physical cash instead. The zero lower bound refers to the limit of lending rates to be sustained at volume much below 0%.

Reserve currencies

Exchange rates

Effects of inflation

Real effects of inflation

If there is unexpected change in money supply, prices will eventually need to update. This could happen immediately, with all prices doubling following a discovery of shells, for example. This would not affect any real (relative) prices.

If, however, some prices are slow to adjust, then their relative prices will change. This would result in prices no longer clearing. If the nominal price of fish is sticky and, prior to inflation, the supply of fish equalled demand for fish, then the inflation would cause the relative price to fall. This would mean that more was demanded than supplied, and output fell.

Price and wage rigidity varies across countries.

Borrowers and savers

If Alice owes Bob 10 shells, and there is a surprise increase in inflation, then Alice is better off and Bob worse off. Expected inflation, or debts in real terms, does not have this issue.

International

Multiple currencies

Previously we have discussed all money being in terms of shells. Either shells or claims on shells. Imagine another bank on a nearby island which has reserves in gold rather than shells. If someone at a shell bank wanted to pay someone at a gold bank, the shell bank would have to sell the shells, use this to buy gold, and send the gold to the gold bank. This is similar to how different countries trade with each other today.

Creating a new currency base can be lucrative. If someone collected a large amount of gold before gold was the base of currency, the value of that would increase.

Digital currencies are examples of this. Early mining is relatively cheap and can award a large proportion of the total currency. Digital currencies – today at least – aren’t used the same way as other currencies. If you pay someone in bitcoin, you’re sending base currency, in a way that you’re not for other payments.

Optimal currency areas

The optimal area to be covered by a currency depends on fluctuations and trade. Having different currencies allows currencies to devalue, and for sticky price effects to be mitigated. At the same time, use of a single currency makes trade easier

The balance therefore depends on whether a region faces similar price stickiness, similar shocks, and large trade inside the area.

When a shock hits a currency area, and there are different levels of price stickiness across it, we would expect to see some areas hit worse than others. Having labour mobility, and fiscal transfers, can help mitigate the effect of such asymmetric shocks.

In a currency area an asymmetric shock and sticky prices will mean that goods in one region will be higher or lower in real terms than in equilibrium. This can cause persistent current account surpluses, as seen in the EU.

Impossible trinity

As inflation rates determine movements in the exchange rate, a central bank cannot at the same time:

  • Control inflation;

  • Control exchange rates; and

  • Allow free capital flows.

Capital controls

If a government can prevent investors from freely choosing between investing in different countries, then interest parity does not apply.

This means that an investor with assets in the lower return country would benefit from getting around such controls.

Internal and external adjustment

We discussed above how nominal prices can be sticky. With trade this becomes more complex, as exchange rates can rapidly move.

A price may be sticky in pounds, but with a flexible exchange rate the price in dollars can rapidly change, and disequilibrium effects can be reduced.

Shadow banking

Shadow banking

Non-banks also undertake lending. If an investment vehicle attracts savers and uses this money to lend to a company, this also increases the money supply, even though the investment vehicle is not a deposit taking bank.